Good things can be sold for expensive prices. Expensive things, however, aren’t necessarily good.
Good average return can cause investors to tolerate high variances in return. High variances in return do not guarantee a good average return.
Good things can be sold for expensive prices. Expensive things, however, aren’t necessarily good.
Good average return can cause investors to tolerate high variances in return. High variances in return do not guarantee a good average return.
A basket of investments available to a manager, who has $X to invest and wants to maximize NPV. The investments are represented in the form of completely certain cashflows. What is the optimal choice?
Since NPVs add linearly, you want to pick the cashflows with the highest NPVs. What restricts you from picking all the investments?
Well, the restriction is that at no point in time should your total sum in cash be less than zero.
So there, given a set of cash flows, it’s a discrete math problem of picking the set of cash flows that form the largest NPV, but do not run the initial investment sum below zero at any time.
—
In reality, knowledge of investments doesn’t come in the form of well-defined cash flows–but this is some basic theory which should be known by anyone who needs to think with these terms. Know what they mean!
Where is return on assets in all this? The type of decision making that ROA enables invokes the existence of options as implied by the one cashflow whose ROA is being examined (i.e., the ability to acquire more of the cashflow with the same profile, but starting at later times, or the ability to sell the asset for some fixed linearly-depreciated amount of its purchase price).
Without considering the optionality of cutting off a cash flow or growing similar profile cash flows using lessons learned for the first one, measures like return on assets (and the income statement view of investment) are meaningless. Refer to the previous post for more information.
Analysis by income statements imply a specific structure of optionality, i.e., the ability to add more assets to get more return in a certain ratio. This is why certain line items are marked as one-time expenses / writedowns–they are there to maintain the optionality structure being communicated. When choosing between different investments, using the NPV view vs. the ROA view depends on how unique of an opportunity the investment entails and what other possibilities the single cashflow implies the existence of.
A business buys assets and using those assets to convert less valuable input into more valuable output.
A business can do one of three things with any given asset:
When you compare options 1 and 2, what you want to understand is how much it would cost you to grow your business or to replace the assets that are degrading away. This is often approximated with the book value of your assets, and that approximation can be improved by adjusting for inflation and otherwise actually thinking about how much you can buy new assets for (the asking price). You compare this to the gross margin you get from utilizing the assets, or the ROA (return on assets), and that is in turn compared to the cost of capital.
If ROA is very low, you then think about selling the asset, and are comparing options 1 and 3. Instead of considering the replacement value of the asset you now consider the sale value (the bid price) of the asset–if the margin divided by the sale value is lower than the cost of capital, you would choose to sell the asset.
—
Considering all this, then, what is the difference between an unprofitable company posting a low return on assets compared to posting a write-down? (In the former, you are using a large denominator with a small numerator, while in the latter you are incurring a one-time loss followed by a higher profit level.)
The difference comes in when you consider what use those book values would be put to in the future. The book value’s primary function is as a proxy to replacement or sale value, and so if the assets in question can be bought for less they should be written down, and if they can be sold for more money they should be revalued upwards.
For example, a company that finds out it had overpaid 50% for some machinery it bought should write down that machinery, because that then gives the right signal with regard to whether it should expand or not, i.e., it should show off its ability to use cheaper fixed capital input to generate a given level of gross margin.
Writedowns are used to calibrate decision making and there is a definite correct way to do them!
Meritocracy and democracy are different criteria, and as such are capable of conflicting with each other. The issue of job creation is centered squarely on this conflict.
On one hand, you have the libertarian allegorical where
Prof. Friedman visited China in the early 1960s and was taken by a government official to see a public works project. Chinese workers were building a canal. Friedman was struck by seeing everyone digging the canal with shovels. Friedman asked the official, “why no heavy earth-moving equipment?” The official said, “oh, this is a jobs program.” So Friedman then says to the official, “then why don’t you just give them spoons instead of shovels to create even more jobs?”
which tells us that employment isn’t desirable in of itself–it is value creation which is needed in the long run. Job creation using public money is tantamount to wealth distribution, which at best reduces the incentive for people to work hard to accumulate wealth, and slows down the economy as a result, and at worst destroys value by funding activities for which the output is of less value than the input.
This isn’t the only viable conceptual model, however. Unequal distribution of resources leads to problems too. There is the more theoretical toy model approach to seeing this, but also accounts that address the effect of monopolies (or oligopolies) on productive competition.
That last article, “Who Broke America’s Jobs Machine?,” tries to pin the lack of job creation in the US on the concentration of market power in big corporates. It breaks down the overall effect into three factors:
The consolidation factor is most interesting to me.
In support of monopoly is the Schumpeterian justification, that the concentration of wealth in the hands of good capital allocators (be they monopolies or the wealthy minority) is what allows investment to take place proper, since surplus is what enables creative high-risk-high-return capital use.
The article weighs in against consolidation, and I understand the argument advanced as such:
Basically, if somehow it is more profitable to the controlling individuals (the managers) to struggle for a bigger slice (rent seek), rather than enlarge the pie, the pie will grow slower.
All these hypotheses are plausible to me–clear empirical borders between them will have to be drawn for their relative truth-hood to be ascertained.